Corporate virtue in India
Financial Express, December 28, 2012
Corporate virtue in India
In previous columns, I discussed the concept of virtuous
growth, which encompasses inclusive growth. Virtuous growth includes
promoting fairness, but it also means avoiding societal change that
corrupts and degrades positive human values. I discussed how virtuous
growth might be promoted in practical terms, in the realms of governance
and civil society. Here I want to discuss the role of business,
specifically large firms that are India’s leading institutions of
capitalism. What can and should their role be?
One idea of virtue is that of corporate social responsibility
(CSR). This is fine as far as it goes, but it does not preclude a firm
making large profits through unethical business behaviour and then
allocating a small amount for superficial do-good efforts. Business
tycoons also set up charitable foundations with their wealth, but, like
CSR, these have no impact on the manner of doing business. The key
desideratum is more ethical behaviour at the core of business practices.
One problem in effecting better business behaviour is that
corruption is endemic in Indian society. The corruption scandals that
are so common in government functioning also involve corruption by
private sector firms. People in government demand bribes, and people in
business supply them, in an unholy equilibrium. How can this equilibrium
be changed? Kaushik Basu’s proposal to decriminalise bribe-giving (but
not bribe-taking) focused on situations in which individuals are
entitled to a government service but are forced to make illegal payments
to receive it. At the Delhi Economics Conclave earlier this month,
Avinash Dixit of Princeton offered a different focus and proposal for
reducing corporate corruption.
If corporations need government approvals, or are competing for
government as a client, they may pay bribes to avoid being at a
competitive disadvantage if “everyone else is doing it.” Dixit proposes
to address this problem through collective action mechanisms. In
particular, he advocates self-regulation by the major industry
associations, with clear codes of ethical conduct, explicit pledges, and
mechanisms for punishing violations. The judicial system would have to
create a framework for recognising such extra-judicial mechanisms, just
as it does in the case of special arbitration. Existing examples of such
institutions are university and military honour codes, and the workings
of local associations to manage common pool resources (studying which
earned Elinor Ostrom an Economics “Nobel”). Implementing such mechanisms
is not easy, nor are they ever perfect, but they can work.
Dixit’s proposal is important as well as timely. Here I describe
developments on the Indian institutional side, which complement his
theoretical nuances. Interestingly, private sector bribery is not even a
criminal offence in many cases. The government drafted a Bill in 2011,
and it is circulating for comments. Major industry associations such as
the Confederation of Indian Industry (CII) and the Federation of Indian
Chambers of Commerce and Industry (FICCI) have come out in support of
the Bill. Changing the legal playing field is an important start to
institutional reform, and complements Dixit’s ideas. Ideally, some of
the practical monitoring and enforcement tasks would be assigned to an
independent regulator, as they are in the US or UK.
Closer to Dixit’s idea is last year’s proposal by CII, of a Code
of Business Ethics for its members. While the draft code is too vague
and broad in many places, it is categorically against corruption,
including all bribe-giving. BS Raghavan, in the Hindu Business Line, has
made specific suggestions for increasing the specificity of the
requirements of the code, and raising levels of transparency with
respect to lobbying and influence activities. Dixit’s proposal would
strengthen this effort even further, with sanctions against violators.
It is surprising that there has not been more public debate on this
effort, and discussion of how to get it right. In fact, none of the
other major industry associations appears to have followed CII’s lead.
Also just a few months ago, the Global Compact Network India
(GCNI), an arm of the United Nations Global Compact, released a report
‘Raising the Bar Through Collective Action: Anti-Corruption Efforts in
Action in India.’ The report release gained much attention, but there
appears to have been no follow-up: the document is nowhere to be found
on the Web. Press releases suggest that the report consists of a few
case studies featuring transparency, monitoring and public standards of
behaviour, together with advice for more collective action. Exactly!
In a sense, industry associations do not need GCNI’s report—they
know what they have to do. But public debate has to push them into
moving forward, to enshrine the ethical best practices that some of
India’s iconic companies already have in place. In the short run, this
will be difficult, as a critical mass of acceptance has to be reached.
CII’s effort has broken the ice, and the other industry associations
should follow its lead, or even leapfrog it, in creating and enforcing
anti-corruption codes. In the long run, raising standards of corporate
behaviour on this front will benefit those firms that can do well by
being more efficient or innovative, not by bribing. This will enhance
growth in the long run and make it politically more sustainable.
No comments:
Post a Comment