India’s inflation puzzle
Financial Express, February 14, 2013
India’s inflation puzzle
India has been struggling with high inflation for over two years.
The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) gradually raised its policy interest
rate and has held it relatively firm, with only two small cuts coming
recently. Meanwhile, economic growth has slowed dramatically. It has
been asserted that RBI’s policy has contributed significantly to the
growth slowdown. It has also been argued that monetary policy is
ineffective in India, given structural rigidities and incomplete markets
in the country’s economy. Fiscal policy and commodity prices have also
been under the spotlight. What do we really know?
A couple of weeks ago, Deepak Mohanty, an executive director
of RBI, gave a speech in which he tackled India’s inflation puzzle. I
will outline what he said, and then assess the arguments. Mr Mohanty
first pointed out that India’s recent inflation surge and its
persistence did not line up well with either its own history or what has
been happening contemporaneously in the rest of the world. World
inflation rose somewhat with the recovery from the Great Recession, but
then moderated, while India’s inflation climbed to double digits. In
India, moreover, a sharp growth slowdown seemed to do nothing to bring
inflation down.
Mr Mohanty traces the start of India’s inflation spike to rises
in the global prices of food, crude oil and other commodities. He refers
to an unidentified analysis that pass-through of global price shocks to
domestic prices increased in this recent period, and notes that
corporate finance data are consistent with this increased pass-through.
The depreciation of the rupee made the pass-through of external
inflation that much worse. Mr Mohanty goes on to note the substantial
increase in demand for higher-protein foods. He further documents the
rise in real wages in rural India. He highlights the fiscal stimulus
that coincided with the recession, and asserts that “higher fiscal
expansion also impedes efficacy of monetary policy transmission.”
Finally, Mr Mohanty emphasises that long-term inflation expectations
rose in this period.
In examining the conduct of monetary policy as inflation spiked,
Mr Mohanty emphasises that rises in interest rates trailed inflation, so
that, starting from historically low interest rates, the real policy
rate remained negative: “Thus, monetary policy was still accommodative
though the extent of accommodation was gradually closing.” While all the
other points made by Mr Mohanty have been widely recognised and
detailed, it seems to me that this feature of recent monetary policy
conduct has not received enough attention. Another important point that
he highlights is that RBI’s estimate of India’s potential output growth
rate has been reduced from 8.5% to 7%.
The story above is plausible, and draws on many analysts’
judgements. I have not been able to identify a publicly available
structural model of the Indian economy that would allow one to say that
the explanations above are the right ones, or to quantify their
different contributions to India’s recent inflation experience. Formal,
comprehensive empirical modelling is always a nice check on judgements
that are necessarily fragmented and somewhat subjective. In the absence
of a model, let me offer some additional thoughts, which may undercut
the notion that India’s recent inflation experience should have been
puzzling.
First, the monetary policy tightening was actually slow and even
hesitant. There may have been good political and economic reasons for
this, including fears about derailing an uncertain recovery, but RBI was
neither choking off inflation nor growth in an assertive manner.
Furthermore, RBI was not doing a good job of managing inflation
expectations—interest rate hikes sometimes came with statements doubting
if they would be effective. Sharper, faster interest rate hikes and
confident statements would have worked. There is no puzzle in the
experience.
Second, focusing on rising individual prices or on accommodative
fiscal policy are both misleading. Yes, there can be short-term
cost-push effects, and government deficits add to aggregate demand. But
economic theory tells us that inflation is fundamentally a monetary
phenomenon, having to do with the aggregate price level. The so-called
fiscal theory of the price level, according to the best theoretical
economic research that I have found, can tell us something about
transmission channels, but not about long-run inflation.
Third, the growth slowdown has more to do with domestic political
events that started to destroy India’s growth potential, more than RBI
has estimated. The level of uncertainty for the private sector jumped.
It is also true, I think, that government deficits have crowded out
private investment directly. So fiscal policy has hurt potential growth.
Global uncertainties and anaemic recoveries, especially in Europe, but
also in the United States, have also worked to reduce potential output
growth in India.
In sum, monetary policy was too timid, and failed to use the
power of the word to complement actions; domestic economic management
was dysfunctional in ways that reduced potential growth, while failing
to account for structural changes in the economy; and global economic
conditions exacerbated domestic policy shortcomings. This is a story
with clear lessons and no puzzle.
No comments:
Post a Comment